PDF Summary:Nudge, by

Book Summary: Learn the key points in minutes.

Below is a preview of the Shortform book summary of Nudge by Richard H. Thaler and Cass R. Sunstein. Read the full comprehensive summary at Shortform.

1-Page PDF Summary of Nudge

Every day we face choices—what to order at a restaurant, what clothes to buy at a store, what show to stream after work. We make these choices without realizing how the way they’re presented affects us. If grocery stores didn’t stock candy at the register, would we eat less of it? If we had to “opt out” of being organ donors rather than “opt in,” would the organ donor pool grow?

In Nudge, Nobel Prize-winning economist Richard Thaler and legal scholar Cass Sunstein examine how the way choices are designed and structured can “nudge” us toward better decisions. In this guide, you’ll learn why people make bad investment choices and how Thaler and Sunstein propose to revitalize the institution of marriage (by abolishing it). You’ll also find commentary on the psychological research underlying Nudge’s concepts as well as more recent data that sheds new light on Thaler and Sunstein’s findings.

(continued)...

(Shortform note: Nudges can also be used to take advantage of the layperson. For example, a financial firm might nudge a naive client toward an investment that benefits the firm itself more than the investor.)

How to Design Choices

Thaler and Sunstein name six primary techniques a choice designer can use to structure a set of options in order to nudge people toward the best decision: offer defaults, draw a map, narrow the field, offer incentives, anticipate error, and emphasize outcomes. Of these, the authors spend the most time examining the first four—offer defaults, draw a map, narrow the field, and offer incentives. We’ll look at each more closely below:

Offer Defaults

Thaler and Sunstein’s most versatile nudge is providing a default—a choice that’s automatically made if the chooser does nothing.

The theory underlying this style of nudge is people’s innate status quo bias, which says that when faced with a choice, many people will choose to either do nothing or stick with their initial choice, even if the new choices are superior to that initial choice.

(Shortform note: Status quo bias is related to two other biases: inertia and loss aversion. Inertia describes the human tendency toward inaction. Loss aversion describes the tendency to psychologically feel losses more strongly than gainsstudies show that people overvalue losses to gains by approximately 2:1, causing them, on occasion, to make riskier decisions to avoid loss. Loss aversion also encourages inertia, as people tend to stick to their original decisions rather than risk losses through change.)

Thaler and Sunstein apply the default nudge to a number of areas, including investment choices.

Defaults to Improve Investment Choices

Thaler and Sunstein note that not long ago, the most common retirement plan offered by employers was a “defined benefit” plan—that is, one that made fixed payments to the beneficiary based on tenure and salary. Now, the most common type of retirement benefit is a “defined contribution” plan, in which employees make periodic contributions to a tax-sheltered investment account, on the assumption that they’ll get back an increased return in later years.

(Shortform note: In 2020, 64% of private industry workers had access to a defined contribution plan while only 15% had access to defined benefit plans. In 1990, those numbers were 34% and 35%, respectively, showing that slightly more people used defined benefit plans in the past.)

This shift put a greater decision-making burden on workers. What level of risk am I willing to take, and how do I allocate my savings accordingly? Should I be investing in stocks or bonds or both? How often should I revisit my allocation of assets, and what real-world information should I be looking for to know when to change it?

According to classically trained economists, we should have no trouble making the right investment choices. This is because, in most economic models of human behavior, people are thought of as eminently rational and self-interested actors who consistently make the best decisions for themselves—that is, people are homo economicus.

The Critique of Homo Economicus

Introduced by classical economists like Adam Smith and John Stuart Mill, the term homo economicus—“economic man”—conceives of people as predictably rational and self-interested, thus able to make the most beneficial economic choices for themselves. In most of the economics research of the last century, people are modeled in just this way: as able to maximize their own economic benefit.

With the advent of behavioral psychology and economics, however, researchers have established that homo economicus is a fiction—that people’s rationality is limited by many cognitive and contextual factors. (In fact, one study determined that real people who meet all the criteria of homo economicus might be diagnosed as psychopathic.) Thus, much of the economics literature rests on a flawed assumption and so can’t be applied to real-world policy.

Debates are ongoing about the accuracy of economic models that rely on homo economicus. Some commentators find that people do in fact act consistently and self-interestedly when faced with decisions while others maintain homo economicus is a chimera. Thaler and Sunstein, for their part, fall into the latter camp, arguing that “Econs”—or “economic people”—simply do not exist.

If people indeed met the criteria of homo economicus, we would have no trouble (1) recognizing that stocks outperform bonds historically and (2) calculating our tolerance for risk based on the probability distribution of stock market returns. But, because we’re human, the complexities and variability of defined-contribution plans cause us to make mistakes that end up—quite literally—costing us.

One way to remedy these mistakes, Thaler and Sunstein argue, is better defaults, specifically “target maturity funds” that automatically reallocate their asset mix based on a worker’s age. A target maturity fund will have a riskier asset allocation—more stocks, fewer bonds—when a worker is young and gradually recalibrate as the worker ages. By the time the worker retires, his portfolio will be heavily weighted toward fixed income assets like bonds. In other words, the “target maturity fund” will have done all the benefit maximizing on behalf of its investor.

Nassim Nicholas Taleb explores the biases that make people bad at assessing risk in his book Fooled by Randomness, in which he argues that when we make decisions, we are typically guided by our primitive brain, which runs on emotion, likes simplicity, and has trouble understanding abstract concepts. When investing, we therefore do things like act impulsively, sell a stock too soon if it’s doing poorly (even if its long-term prospects are good), and misjudge our abilities to play the stock market—in reality, it’s luck that rules the market and determines most success, not our skill in choosing stocks.

Thaler and Sunstein’s solution of using targeted maturity funds to sidestep our natural impulses addresses Taleb’s concerns, as it takes the decision-making process away from our primitive brain and relies instead on rational algorithms.

Draw a Map

A carefully engineered default combats the human tendency toward inertia and the status quo, but how can a choice designer help active choosers navigate complicated decisions?

One way, according to Thaler and Sunstein, is to draw choosers a map that shows them where their options will bring them if they settle on one option or another—an outline that explicitly connects their choices to outcomes.

To help choice designers effectively draw a map, Thaler and Sunstein advise that regulators mandate transparency programs whereby companies would be required to provide consumers with more—and more clearly organized—information about their products so that consumers can better compare choices and make the right decision.

By presenting us with clearer information, a transparency program could help combat our tendency to use rules of thumb, and help us see more clearly the potential outcomes of our decisions.

Are Transparency Programs Actually a Nudge?

In some of Thaler and Sunstein’s examples of transparency programs, they conflate disclosures made before a transaction with those made after it. For example, Thaler and Sunstein categorize both of the following as transparency:

  • A cellular service enumerating all of its fees, including real-life examples, before a person purchases the service

  • A cellular service providing its customers with a detailed report listing all the ways a person actually used the service and the fees that person incurred

The problem with classifying the second example as a nudge is that it’s helpful only after the person has already made a choice. In other words, under that scenario, we might make a terrible initial choice and receive our “nudge” only when we get the detailed report. The transparency, therefore, doesn’t change our behavior during the decision-making process and therefore is not an actual nudge.

Some critics of the book have pointed out as much, arguing that some of what Thaler and Sunstein press for is merely more transparency, which is hardly a revolutionary idea.

Credit Cards

Thaler and Sunstein note that transparency programs would be especially helpful for consumers with credit cards.

Credit cards are a primary vehicle for US indebtedness, and Thaler and Sunstein produce an array of statistics that illustrate their centrality to Americans’ personal finances, including the average number of credit cards per cardholder (8.5) and the average American’s credit card debt ($8,000).

(Shortform note: However, Americans’ debt situation has changed significantly since Nudge’s publication (and the corrective of the 2008 financial crisis). Whereas, in 2007, the credit card debt of the average American household was around $8,000, as of March 2021 it was $6,741.)

Thaler and Sunstein’s solution to the spendthrift effects of credit cards is a credit card-specific transparency program.

They propose requiring credit card companies to send cardholders a detailed annual statement featuring not only the year’s purchases but also the year’s fees, interest charges, and penalties. This information would make the true cost of our credit card spending clearer to us and allow us to more easily compare cards.

(Shortform note: The Credit Card Accountability Responsibility and Disclosure Act of 2009 (Credit CARD act) took steps toward making their idea a reality. The act outlawed many of credit card companies’ most unsavory practices, including raising interest rates arbitrarily and giving cardholders insufficient time to pay their debts before incurring a penalty. It also nudged credit card companies to provide (1) simpler and more transparent agreements and (2) more information in their statements, including target dates for paying off the card if the cardholder only made minimum payments. In addition, most credit cards’ online banking interfaces offer annual reports as well as real-time transaction information.)

Narrow the Field

Thaler and Sunstein are firm believers in people’s right to choose (hence the libertarian half of libertarian paternalism). But they also recognize that too much choice can be overwhelming and counterproductive. (Shortform note: Researchers refer to this as choice overload or the Paradox of Choice: We want more options because we think it maximizes our chances of making the best choice, but having too many choices paralyzes us.)

One way to narrow the field is simply to offer fewer options. However, since this limits choices, which Thaler and Sunstein oppose (as it contradicts libertarianism), they propose another way of narrowing the field of options: grouping and structuring the choice set to make it more manageable.

For example, many retirement plans offer “tiered” investment choices. Rather than hand enrollees a voluminous and undifferentiated list of funds to choose from, retirement plans will offer, say, three different tiers, each corresponding to enrollees’ level of investment interest and experience.

(Shortform note: Because choices aren’t limited in a tiered system, this type of nudge isn’t foolproof: If an inexpert but risk-seeking enrollee wants to bet her retirement on the most aggressive and fee-laden actively managed fund, she’s free to do so, even if it could result in catastrophe.)

Offer Incentives

Old-fashioned incentives, financial or otherwise, can nudge choosers toward better decisions. The key to a successful incentive, argue Thaler and Sunstein, is to make its benefits relevant and obvious to the person making the choice.

Economists have long noted the power of incentives in driving human behavior—the concept underpins a capitalist society. Most economists agree that the primary incentives that drive behavior are self-interested incentives. As outlined in Charles Wheelan’s Naked Economics, when people work to benefit themselves, they generally benefit others as well (as when they work to earn a salary, what they produce raises the standard of living for others).

This is not always cut-and-dried, though—different people will be motivated by different wants, which makes an economist’s job difficult when identifying incentives that will motivate large numbers of people. However, Thaler and Sunstein’s proposals aim to appeal to the majority through simplicity: No one wants to pay more than they need to for an item or service, and the authors’ nudges bank on that.

Thaler and Sunstein suggest that an area ripe for incentives is environmental policy, in particular policies to reduce carbon emissions.

Reducing Atmospheric Carbon Through Incentives

Thaler and Sunstein are advocates of a “cap-and-trade” mechanism for reducing greenhouse gases.

In a cap-and-trade system, the government sets a ceiling (the “cap”) on a certain pollutant—say, carbon dioxide—and confers on industries and firms rights to pollute up to that amount. If a firm chooses to reduce its emissions below the cap, it can “trade” its excess cap space to other companies for cash. According to Thaler and Sunstein, a cap-and-trade system meets the principles of libertarian paternalism because it preserves choice while nudging firms, through economic incentives, to clean up their operations.

(Shortform note: While a cap-and-trade system in operation might conform to the precepts of libertarian paternalism, its creation and implementation almost certainly don’t. That is, there’s no way to “nudge” Thaler and Sunstein’s cap-and-trade model into existence—it has to be created by top-down government rulemaking (in other words, paternalism). Moreover, cap-and-trade, at least when instituted at the state level, has produced mixed results, leading many commentators to advocate broader and more explicitly paternalistic interventions.)

Want to learn the rest of Nudge in 21 minutes?

Unlock the full book summary of Nudge by signing up for Shortform.

Shortform summaries help you learn 10x faster by:

  • Being 100% comprehensive: you learn the most important points in the book
  • Cutting out the fluff: you don't spend your time wondering what the author's point is.
  • Interactive exercises: apply the book's ideas to your own life with our educators' guidance.

Here's a preview of the rest of Shortform's Nudge PDF summary:

PDF Summary Shortform Introduction

...

Connect With Thaler

Cass R. Sunstein

Cass R. Sunstein is a professor at Harvard Law School and the founder and director of the Program on Behavioral Economics and Public Policy there. Sunstein holds a BA from Harvard College and a JD from Harvard Law School and has taught at the University of Chicago. He also clerked for Supreme Court Justice Thurgood Marshall.

The author of hundreds of articles and dozens of books, Sunstein is known among legal scholars as an expert in constitutional law (he is the coauthor of a constitutional law casebook widely used in US law schools). He is also one of the most-cited legal scholars of all time for his work on constitutional, administrative, and environmental law.

In early 2009, Sunstein was named President Obama’s regulatory czar in the White House Office of Information and Regulatory Affairs (OIRA), which oversees all federal regulations. Because...

PDF Summary Part 1: Overview of Biases, Libertarian Paternalism, and Nudges

...

Some of the biases that Thaler and Sunstein discuss in the book, upon which many of their nudges rely, include:

  • The anchoring bias—when we take a fact we know (or think we know) and adjust it to account for a fact we don’t (such as when an auction opens the bidding at a high number because people associate a high price with value and will therefore see that object as valuable (Shortform note: Impulsive decision-making favors anchoring bias, so using a simple checklist can help you overcome it.)
  • The availability bias—when we answer questions and make judgments on the basis of whether comparable examples come readily to mind rather than statistical probability (if you hear a story of someone surviving a deadly disease, you’re likely to think it’s less deadly than the statistics show) (Shortform note: In business, you can avoid availability bias by [creating diverse teams and seeking broad...

PDF Summary Part 2: Designing Choices—Overview

...

  1. They’ll offer incentives to encourage healthier eating. (For example, a child might earn extra TV time for each piece of fruit he or she eats.)

Choice Design and Paternalism

The use of parenting as an analogue for Thaler and Sunstein’s choice designer points to the fundamental question the authors are at pains to address: How is choice design different from straight-up paternalism? Isn’t designing a choice system—say, a company retirement plan—to effect certain outcomes just like a parent mandating certain choices for his child?

There are two key aspects of choice design that undermine its paternalism:

First, (some kind of) choice design is inevitable. Picture any choice you’ve had to make, from the most commonplace (choosing which brand of AA batteries to buy) to the most consequential (deciding whether to undergo a particular kind of medical treatment). Each of these choices comes with a particular choice structure, whether purposefully designed or not: A store clerk just happens to put the Energizer batteries at eye level, or your doctor presents the therapeutic options in terms of their success rates rather than failure rates. Because of...

What Our Readers Say

This is the best summary of Nudge I've ever read. I learned all the main points in just 20 minutes.

Learn more about our summaries →

PDF Summary Technique 1: Offer Defaults

...

The authors recommend automatically enrolling employees in a retirement plan—that is, making enrollment the default—and offering an option to opt out of the plan. They posit that due to people’s status quo bias and tendency toward inertia, most of these employees won’t bother to disenroll, thereby ensuring those employees at least some personal retirement savings.

Research has shown this method to work. One study found that, under an opt-in approach—meaning employees have to choose to enroll in their 401(k)—participation in a particular retirement plan was 20% three months after hire, growing to 65% within 36 months. When the plan adopted automatic enrollment, new-employee enrollment jumped to 90% and grew to 96% within 36 months.

(Shortform note: Some researchers have disputed the efficacy of auto-enrollment in retirement plans, finding that, in some cases, the retirement savings generated by auto-enrollment were offset by a rise in personal debt. The explanation for this finding...

PDF Summary Technique 2: Draw a Map

...

Thaler and Sunstein examine two areas in particular where, because of their natural complexity, transparency programs can greatly help consumers: mortgages and credit cards.

Mortgages

The contemporary mortgage market is dauntingly complex. Mortgage shoppers now have to know the difference between fixed-rate loans (whose interest rate stays the same for the life of the loan) and variable-rate loans (whose interest rate fluctuates with the market), recognize teaser rates (a lower initial rate that often balloons after that initial period ends), and somehow take into account fees (administrative charges by the issuer), points (payments that result in lower interest rates), and penalties (for example, for paying off the loan early).

(Shortform note: Nudge was published in the earliest stages of the 2008 financial crisis and the consequent changes to US financial regulations, many of which were aimed at addressing the very problems Thaler and Sunstein discuss. The most profound change, arguably, was the Dodd-Frank Wall Street Reform and Consumer Protection Act. This law created the Consumer Financial Protection Bureau (CFPB), which **regulates consumer financial...

PDF Summary Techniques 3 and 4: Narrow the Field and Offer Incentives

...

One way to narrow the field is simply to offer fewer options. However, since this limits choices, which Thaler and Sunstein oppose (as it contradicts libertarianism), they propose another way of narrowing the field of options: grouping and structuring the choices to make them more manageable.

For example, many retirement plans offer “tiered” investment choices; rather than hand enrollees a voluminous and undifferentiated list of funds to choose from, retirement plans will offer, say, three different tiers, each corresponding to enrollees’ level of investment interest and experience. In this kind of choice structure, Tier 1 might feature a single default target maturity fund; Tier 2, a small collection of funds, each with a different mix of assets to represent conservative, moderate, and aggressive positions; and Tier 3, the full complement of funds for the savvy investor who wants total control over her investments. In this example, choices are structured but not limited.

(Shortform note: Because choices aren’t limited in a tiered system, it isn’t foolproof: If an inexpert but risk-seeking enrollee wants to bet her retirement on the most aggressive and...

PDF Summary Part 3: Controversial and Miscellaneous Nudges

...

(Shortform note: The right to waive one’s right to sue satisfies the libertarian half of libertarian paternalism, but the question is: Would it actually reduce health care costs? Thaler and Sunstein acknowledge that the research they cite on the cost impact of liability insurance is “controversial and may be exaggerated”; in fact, most researchers have determined that malpractice insurance costs comprise a tiny portion of total health care spending. One study published in Health Affairs, for example, found that the medical liability system only accounts for 2.4% of total health care spending.)

Renaming Marriage

Thaler and Sunstein wade into the then-controversial subject of same-sex marriage. They argue that all sides in the debate of whether to allow it or not could be satisfied if the legal licensing of marriage was separated from the religious aspect of it. They thus propose that the government stop issuing “marriage” licenses and instead issue licenses for civil unions, which would deny no one based on gender or sexuality, thereby leaving marriage to be regulated by religious organizations...

Why are Shortform Summaries the Best?

We're the most efficient way to learn the most useful ideas from a book.

Cuts Out the Fluff

Ever feel a book rambles on, giving anecdotes that aren't useful? Often get frustrated by an author who doesn't get to the point?

We cut out the fluff, keeping only the most useful examples and ideas. We also re-organize books for clarity, putting the most important principles first, so you can learn faster.

Always Comprehensive

Other summaries give you just a highlight of some of the ideas in a book. We find these too vague to be satisfying.

At Shortform, we want to cover every point worth knowing in the book. Learn nuances, key examples, and critical details on how to apply the ideas.

3 Different Levels of Detail

You want different levels of detail at different times. That's why every book is summarized in three lengths:

1) Paragraph to get the gist
2) 1-page summary, to get the main takeaways
3) Full comprehensive summary and analysis, containing every useful point and example